Adam Smith and the Myth of Laissez Faire
Jonathan Finegold Catalán reviews (7 June) The Clash of Economic
Ideas: The Great Policy Debates and Experiments of the Last Hundred Years by Lawrence H. White, Cambridge
University Press, 2012 HERE
“Adam Smith’s Distrust of Business”
“While
The Clash of Economic Ideas
does not put too great of stress on it, White does go to some length to make
sure the reader walks away knowing that Smith placed value on laissez-faire only because he saw it
as a restraint on the evils of the businessman. To some, this seems
difficult to fit in with the idea that Smith stands for, essentially, an
unbridled market, the classical conception of freedom and liberty, and the
pursuit of self-interest. One explanation might be the “bleeding heart”
one, showing the compatibility between capitalism and the welfare of society’s
poorest members. Certainly, this was one of Smith’s interests when
defending the market economy in The
Wealth of Nations. But, his general support of the market follows
a much more fundamental insight.
Smith
saw mercantilism as a process of collusion between the State and merchants,
allowing the latter to take advantage of the former’s monopoly on force for
their own benefit and against the well-being of the average consumer. He
did not recognize the State as an effective tool to restrain the potential
damages that self-interest could wreak in a completely unrestrained
environment. Rather, Smith saw the market as the mechanism of restraint;
it is the market which increases competition between merchants, figuratively
enslaving them to the wants of the consumer. This “macroeconomic”
interpretation may stem from his views on the division of labor, which he also
saw as a restraint on the actions of men. Indeed, the division of labor
makes all dependent on others, meaning that one needs to produce to the benefit
of others in order to earn the income to consume for one’s own wellbeing.
Inter-dependency and competition jointly restrain the producer in favor of the
welfare of society as a whole.
While
Smith may be rightfully invoked against some of the modern arguments in favor
of intervention, as does White, one must be wary of
overuse. Our author notes at least one exception to Smith’s support for
capitalism: public goods. In cases where the market cannot guarantee the
existence of competition — as disputed as these are — Smith may have readily
supported interventionism. During his time, he may not have recognized a
great many examples (although, Smith did argue in favor of various forms of
interventionism25), but the modern rise of welfare economics may be
seen as just as Smithian as any modern free-market theory.”
Comment
Let
us be clear: Adam Smith did not use the words “Laissez-faire” in anything that
he wrote, published in his lifetime or posthumous, or in any student notes that
have so far been found, or in any reports of his lectures by those who attended
them (John Millar, James Woodrow, Lord Buchan, John Stuart, etc.,) or by those who
knew him intimately (such as Dugald Stewart, whose father was a student at Glasgow with Smith).
How
Lawrence White knows that “Smith placed value on laissez-faire” or that “he saw it as a restraint on the evils of
the businessman” is not explained (perhaps this is an assertion of the
reviewer?).
We
know that Smith knew of the use and meaning of laissez-faire from his close
association with the Physiocratic circle around Quesnay during his visits to
Paris (1764-67). The fact is that
laissez-faire never entered his vocabulary. Nor did an English translation. This has not prevented many commentators from seeking to use
Smith’s use of Natural Liberty as a synonym for laissez-faire. It was not the same thing.
Natural
Liberty was a philosophical concept based on Natural Law theories as expressed
by Grotius and Pufendorf, the latter of which authored several textbooks in
Latin in wide use across Europe, including the four Scottish Universities (where
all lectures were traditionally taught in Latin, at least in Glasgow up to
Hutcheson and Smith’s classes), Smith was fluent in Latin (and Greek, French and
Italian).
The
originator of laissez-faire was a ‘plain spoken’ French merchant, M. le Gendre,
a deputy of commerce, who responded to the question put to them by Colbert, the
French minister, what he could do for them at a meeting that Colbert convened:
“lassez nous faire’ le Gendre replied in 1690. Those who quote the phrase today
often miss these details. Note that it was a merchant who favoured laissez
faire. Consumers were not asked but are supposed to be the main beneficiaries of laissez-faire.
Smith remained suspicious of merchants who from Elizabethan times had monopolised who could practise their trade and where, in the infamous Town
Guilds. “People of the same trade
seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation
sends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise
prices” (WN I.x.c.27: 145).
Laissez-faire was of dubious benefit, given its claimants hence Smith never advocated it.
He
believed that consumption was the sole end of production and competition was
the antidote to open and secret monopolies. Far from leaving merchants alone, he wanted them under the
pressure of free competition of consumer choice.
Colbert typified state regulations of trade and France was a prime
example where government regulations abounded, with numerous officious Inspectors of
French street markets and fairs inspecting every detail, not to ensure open
competition, but to ensure the State’s passion for order. Absent these regulated orders,enforced by the Inspectors ,the
merchants would have imposed their own orders, and their likely behaviours, if
free to do so, would not have worked for the best interests of their captive
customers. Trade guilds, legal or
unofficial, under the cloak of laissez-faire worked for the interests of
merchants, not consumers.
So
where did cries by merchants and manufacturers for ‘laissez faire come from throughout
the 19th century? Two
French economists, Say and Bastiat, were prominent in cries for laissez-faire,
using Adam Smith’s name as cover for its popularity among politicians and merchant
campaigners against the ‘Corn Laws’ and the newly passed but limited Factory
Acts. The words laissez-faire
are now endemic across the non-socialist political spectrum, particularly in
the USA.
So what
reliance should we place on Jonathan Finegold
Catalán’s claim that “Smith placed value on laissez-faire only because he saw it as a restraint on the evils
of the businessman”?
I
suggest very little. It does
not correspond to the historical facts about Adam Smith and perpetuates a myth
about his advocacy of laissez-fire. He was not beholden to the intentions of merchants and manufacturers - they cannot be trusted - and neither can government Inspectors.
4 Comments:
I used "laissez-faire" as a synonym for "free markets," so I didn't intend to suggest that Smith used the actual term "laissez-faire." Now, that Smith didn't support "free markets" -- then I (and, I think, White) assumed that he did, and perhaps we're wrong. I think, though, that White does routinely consider what you state in your last sentence, and that is basically what I tried to emphasize in that part of the review.
I'm not sure if the first comment went through (not logged in through Google or something -- I'll try again). I didn't mean to suggest that Smith used the actual term "laissez-faire." I used the word "laissez-faire" as a synonym of "free markets" -- perhaps, as you note, incorrectly. That's entirely my fault. It's just that I thought it would be pretty well understood within context (of free markets). Regarding White's book, his coverage of Smith acknowledges pretty much what you write in the very last sentence of this post, and that's what I was trying to reiterate in my review.
Johnathan
Thank you for your posts. The delay between posting and it appearing on the Blog is due to my moderation gateway, brought about by gross abuse from trolls, sex trades, and abuse.
I am not always available to scan for comments, especially when domestic chores and grandchildren are visiting.
Smith was in favour of freer markets. of that there is little doubt. He did not advocate laissez-faire, as asserted in the early 19th century, and now believed passionately today.
His stance, I think is well expressed in the stance of being in favour of 'markets where possible, regulation and intervention where necessary'.
Ideas do matter, both when we get them right and when we get them wrong.
I enjoyed reading your Blog.
Gavin
How did Smith define the term "free market"?
I was under the impression that it meant a market free of privilege, of unearned income, of economic rents. It was a market free from the vestiges of feudalism that rewarded privilege instead of work.
Post a Comment
<< Home