Peter Boettke's Living Economics Published
Peter Boettke is a University
Professor of Economics and Philosophy at George Mason University and director
of the F. A. Hayek Program for Advanced Study in Philosophy, Politics, and
Economics at the Mercatus Center.
Living Economics:
Yesterday, Today, and Tomorrow, by
Peter J. Boettke HERE
This
looks like a most important text for all those interested in Adam Smith’s (and
F. A. Hayek’s) distinct contribution to political economy. Peter published an extract from his new
book on 2 June: “Living Economics Officially Released” HERE
I
am so impressed with the extract that I have re-posted a slightly edited
version on Lost Legacy as well as ordered Peter’s book (hopefully not exposed
to copyright reactions).
I
agree with every sentiment Peter expresses, which presents the main thrust of
Lost Legacy far more eloquently than I have attempted over the years. Peter is still an active teacher
– as visits to Coordination Problem blog demonstrate (bookmark it now for
regular doses of Peter Boettke’s sharp thinking). Note how he puts mainstream economics in its place and
presents Adam Smith’s thinking sharply and without the nonsense of mainstream
economics on the mythical “invisible hand”.
“Living
Economics Officially Released” by Peter Boettke:
“… I use the term
“mainline economics” to describe a set of propositions that were first
significantly advanced in economics by Thomas Aquinas in the thirteenth century
and then the Late Scholastics of the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries at the
University of Salamanca in Spain. . . . These insights were further developed
in economics from the Classical School of Economics (both in its Scottish
Enlightenment version of Adam Smith and the French Liberal tradition of
Jean-Baptiste Say and Frédéric Bastiat), to the early Neoclassical School
(especially the Austrian version of Carl Menger, Ludwig von Mises, and F. A.
Hayek), and finally with the contemporary development of New Institutional
Economics (as reflected in the property rights economics of Armen Alchian and
Harold Demsetz; the new economic history of Douglass North; the law and
economics of Ronald Coase; the Public Choice economics of James Buchanan and
Gordon Tullock; the economics of governance associated with Oliver Williamson
and Elinor Ostrom; and the market process economics of Israel Kirzner). The
core idea in this approach to economics is that there are two fundamental
observations of commercial society: (1) individual pursuit of self-interest,
and (2) complex social order that aligns individual interests with the general
interest.
In the mainline of
economics, the “invisible hand postulate” reconciles self-interest with the
general interest not by collapsing one into the other or by assuming
super-human cognitive capabilities among the actors, but through the
reconciliation process of exchange within specific institutional environments.
It is the “higgling and bargaining” within the market economy, as Adam Smith
argued, that produces social order. The “invisible hand” solution does not
emerge because the mainline economist postulates a perfectly rational
individual interacting with other perfectly rational individuals within a
perfectly structured market, as many critics suppose. Such idealizations would
be as alien to Adam Smith as they would be to F. A. Hayek. Instead, for those
who “sit in the seat of Adam Smith,” man is a very imperfect being operating
within a very imperfect world. Sound economic reasoning, by focusing on
exchange, and the institutions within which exchange takes place, explains how
complex social order emerges through the aid of prices and the entrepreneurial
market process.
The mainline of
economics, in my narrative, is to be contrasted with the “mainstream” of
economic thought. Mainline is defined by a set of positive propositions about
social order that were held in common from Adam Smith onward, but mainstream
economics is a sociological concept related to what is currently fashionable
among the scientific elite of the profession. Often the mainline and the
mainstream dovetail, but at other times they deviate from one another. …
Social Cooperation
Economics
teaches us many things, but to me the most important is how social cooperation
under the division of labor is realized. This is what determines whether
nations are rich or poor; whether the individuals in these nations live in
poverty, ignorance, and squalor or live healthy and wealthy lives full of
possibilities. If the institutions promote social cooperation under the
division of labor, then the gains from trade and innovation will be realized.
But if the institutions, in effect, hinder social cooperation under the
division of labor, then life will devolve into a struggle for daily existence.
Economics, in other words, gives us the key intellectual framework for
understanding how we can live better together.
The mainline of
economic teaching from Adam Smith to Hayek taught not only what economics can
tell us but more importantly what it cannot tell us. There are real limits to
economic analysis and efforts at economic control. The main reasons economics
got off track in the twentieth century are . . . a failure to recognize those
limits and a confusion of the policy sciences with the engineering sciences.
Based on the knowledge of the physical sciences, the engineering sciences
created technological solutions unimaginable to previous generations. My
grandparents entered this world when most travel was conducted by horse and
buggy; they departed this earth in a world which had not only experienced
transatlantic flight but had placed a man on the moon. Since their passing, the
Internet has developed and transformed not only the way we communicate but also
the way we shop, the way we learn, and the way we form social bonds. These
amazing technological advances tend to reinforce the idea that through science
men can conquer any and all problems they face.
But even in this
case of technological innovation, we tend to forget something vital to the
story of progress. Technological knowledge was transformed into useful
knowledge through the ordinary business of commerce. Without the guiding role
of property, prices, and profit/loss accounting, the gains from innovation
would not be realized. The reason for this is simple: Without the guiding
signals and incentives of the price system, economic actors cannot sort out
from the array of technologically feasible projects those that are most
economical to pursue. And absent that economic knowledge, technological
ventures will be plagued by a systemic waste of resources.
Description, Not Design
Commercial
life did not emerge through design but instead out of the human proclivity to
truck, barter, and exchange with one another. Specialization in production and
exchange existed well before economists came up with those terms to help
explain that behavior. Economists, in other words, did not invent the economy
but rather came to their study with the economy already operating and were
tasked with the role of providing philosophic understanding of already existing
practice. This is radically different from the civil engineer who designs the
bridge to ease travel between Manhattan and Brooklyn. The demand by politicians
and the public that economics be more like engineering is perhaps the greatest
corrupting force on the science.
But
if we accept the judgment that economics cannot play the role of social
engineering, we need not be content with economics being purely philosophical.
Economics and political economy are capable of generating significant empirical
information. The discipline can inform us about how alternative institutional
frameworks will impact our ability to realize the gains from trade and
innovation. If the institutional framework impedes trade and innovation, then
those gains will go unrealized; if the institutional framework encourages those
aspects of an economy, then those gains will be realized.
Two Propensities
I
often tell students that humankind has demonstrated two natural propensities—to
truck, barter, and exchange (as Adam Smith taught); and to rape, pillage, and
plunder (as Thomas Hobbes taught us)—and which propensity is pursued is a
function of the institutional framework within which individuals find
themselves living and interacting. The life experience can be a virtuous cycle
of wealth creation and healthier and wealthier lives, or it can be a nasty and
brutish hell on earth. So while economics cannot give us exact point
predictions, it can, as a science, inform us of tendencies and directions of
change as well as the wealth-creating or wealth-destroying capacity of the
political economic system.
…
the political economy of Adam Smith to F. A. Hayek takes humans as they are and
seeks to find the institutional framework that both constrains bad people so
they do the least harm when in positions of power and uses the ordinary
motivations of humans and their limited cognitive capabilities to realize
social cooperation under the division of labor. The mainline economists found
that in the private-property market economy and a constitutionally limited
government . . . individuals’ unique knowledge of time and place could be
marshaled to realize a peaceful and prosperous social order.
Hubris
…
Hubris can come in two forms: a hubris that one is of a higher moral character,
and a hubris that one is of a higher intellectual caliber than one’s fellow
citizens. It is this hubris that Hayek called The Fatal Conceit. The
intellectual culture in which Adam Smith wrote was sympathetic to such a
critique of hubris. . . . The “man of system”—as Smith termed this hubris in The Theory of Moral Sentiments—was
the object of ridicule. Only he would be “wise in his own conceit” or in
possession of the “folly and presumption” to believe he should lord over other
men in their affairs of commerce.
…
Economics since [Ketnes] has been derailed educationally and as a tool for
public policy. It became the handmaiden of the man of system and not the reason
to doubt the wisdom of that conceit of men. We have The Economics of Control
and not the Common Sense of Political Economy.
Economists
are tasked with speaking truth to power, not catering to power. The discipline,
from Smith to Hayek, has taught us about the need to limit power to curb the
predatory capabilities of mankind. … It rests with men whether they will make
the proper use of the rich treasure with which this knowledge provides them or
whether they will leave it unused. But if they fail to take the best advantage
of it and disregard its teachings and warnings, they will not annul economics;
they will stamp out society and the human race.”
Comment
Pure Dead Brilliant, as we say in Scotland.
4 Comments:
"It is the 'higgling and bargaining' within the market economy, as Adam Smith argued, that produces social order.'
Exactly, and the networking and feedback systems that higgling and bargaining produce.
The way Peter Boettke explains it, the invisible hand is pragmatic. It alines the temperament of individuals with the reality of the world, which are often at odds.
airth
Once again you find (5.36pm) in a Lost Legacy post cause to adjust your views of the "invisible hand" to satisfy the theme of a writer I quote from. Read through you many (welcome) comments and note how many aspects of views of others justify your belief in "an invisible hand" ideology, even though others make many claims for what the IH is. Almost entirely my references either undo such notions by reference to Adam Smith use of the IH metaphor, or mock such claims by some others (Loony Tunes series). You are perfectly entitled to believe anything, though I worry sometimes that you are oblivious to the many contradictory claims you make.
Your statement claiming Peter Boetekk explains the IH is "pragmatic" somehow reconciling an individual's sense of temperament to reality philosophically is too obscure for me.
Keep up the good work.
Gavin
Perhaps an essay about the invisible hand being pragmatic would be interesting. I got the idea from Elizabeth Shaw's essay "Is James’s Pragmatism Really a New Name for Some Old Ways of Thinking?: http://commons.pacificu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1402&context=eip
Which raises an interesting question: Is the invisible hand metaphor about some old (and natural) ways of thinking ?
Post a Comment
<< Home