Still Stuck With the Neoclassical Theory of the Firm?
Paul Walker
(21 January) posts on Anti-Dismal Blog
on “on all things to do with economics and related
subjects” HERE
Today’s
debate is about the ‘theory of the firm’ that used to dominate economic
thinking when I was an undergraduate in the 1960s. In it he brings focus on the firm up-to-date and shows that
the once dominant neo-classical theory of the firm from “Arthur Pigou, Lionel Robbins, Jacob
Viner, Joan Robinson or Edward Chamberlin” has been replaced by “Ronald Coase,
Oliver Williamson, Bengt Holmstrom or Oliver Hart”.
Eric Clampton’s post quotes Cameron K Murrays HERE http://ckmurray.blogspot.com.au/
on “Fresh Economic Thinking Blog” leading Paul Walker to query his timing.
“Eric Crampton alerted me to this
posting at the Fresh
economic thinking blog on Time for a
new theory of the firm. The upshot of the posting is that its author
doesn't like the standard neoclassical theory of the firm and thinks we need a
new theory of the firm to replace the neoclassical one. Let me make two quick
comments.
He's a bit out of date. The neoclassical model hasn't
been the mainstream theory of the firm since around the 1970s so the call to
replace it is only 40 odd years too late. The major difference between the
(neoclassical) mainstream theories of the past and the mainstream theories of
the present is that the focus − in terms of the questions the theory attempts
to answer − of the post-1970 mainstream literature is markedly different from
that of the earlier (neoclassical) mainstream theory. The theory of the firm
for Ronald Coase, Oliver Williamson, Bengt Holmstrom or Oliver Hart is a very
different thing from that of Arthur Pigou, Lionel Robbins, Jacob Viner, Joan
Robinson or Edward Chamberlin. The questions the theory seeks to answer have
changed from being about how the firm acts in its various markets; how it
prices its outputs or how it combines its inputs, to questions about the firm’s
existence, boundaries − including the dividing line between state and private
enterprises − and internal organisation. That is, in the mainstream theory
there has been a movement away from seeing the theory of the firm as simply
developing one component (albeit an important component) of price theory,
namely the element concerned with the factor and product market behaviour of
producers, to the theory being concerned with the firm as a important economic
institution in its own right. For anyone who is interested in some of what the
current mainstream in the theory of the firm is I suggest checking out the
forthcoming paper in the Journal of
Economic Surveys entitled "Contracts, Entrepreneurs, Market
Creation and Judgement: The Contemporary Mainstream Theory of the Firm in
Perspective" by ... well .... errr .... modesty forbids me.
There are no firms in the neoclassical
or I suspect in the "replacement" model we are being offered. Both
models work implicitly within zero transaction cost frameworks and within such
settings firms have no role. As Foss (2000) puts it, With perfect and costless
contracting, it is hard to see room for anything resembling firms (even
one-person firms), since consumers could contract directly with owners of
factor services and wouldn't need the services of the intermediaries known as
firms (Foss 2000: xxiv).
Or as Foss, Lando and Thomsen (2000) summarise
things:
[t]he pure analysis of the market institution leaves almost no room for
the firm (Debreu 1959). Under the assumption of a perfect set of contingent
markets, as well as certain other restrictive assumptions, the model describes
how markets may produce efficient outcomes. The question how organizations
should be structured does not arise, because market-contracting perfectly
solves all incentive and coordination issues. By assumption, firm behaviour
(profit maximization) is invariant to institutional form (e.g. ownership
structure). The whole economy can operate efficiently as one great system of
markets, in which autonomous agents enter into very elaborate contracts with
each other. However, by treating the firm itself as a black box, where internal
structure,contracts, etc. disappear from the picture, there are many other
issues that the theory cannot address. For example, the theory does not tell us
why firms exist (Foss, Lando and Thomsen 2000: 632).
In short, you need
incomplete contracts to explain why firms exist.
Refs: Foss,
Nicolai J. (2000). ‘The Theory of the Firm: An Introduction to Themes and
Contributions’. In Nicolai Foss (ed.), The
Theory of the Firm: Critical Perspectives on Business and Management
(pp. xv-lxi), London: Routledge.
Foss, Nicolai J., Henrik Lando and Steen Thomsen (2000). 'The Theory of
the Firm'. In Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest (eds.), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics
(vol. III, pp. 631-58), Cheltenham U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.”
Comment
And much more from Paul Walker which you can read by following the link
HERE
I recommend you do so
especially if you have not kept up with the literature and are still stuck in
the neoclassical model as it used to be taught uncritically and as reverently
believed.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home