Adam Smith On Civil Government
“The
Dreamer” posts (8 December) this piece “Adam Smith: the most misquoted economist of our time.”
HERE on
“Note: I was discussing with a
colleague how frustrated I was when socialists took Adam Smith quotes out of
context. He replied that the right had equally used Smith to support its
dogmas. To be clear, Smith was not a dogmatist, but a pragmatist. I wish to
clarify the context in which he said all these things.”
“Civil government, in so far as it is
instituted for the security of property, is in reality instituted for the
defense of the rich against the poor, or of those who have some property
against those who have none at all. – Adam
Smith, Wealth of Nations, Book V, Chapter I, Part II On the Expense of Justice.”
“Smith
was talking about the origins of civil government here and how no effective
institutions for the regulation of property were put in place without
significant corruption. Further in the chapter, Smith elaborates on the
necessity of a separation of powers to ensure fair judgment of the Rule of Law
to promote egalitarian treatment. A fair justice system will ensure that both
the rich and the poor have property rights.”
Comment
I discussed this quotation from Smith on Lost Legacy 29 July way back in
2006:
“Taking a quotation out of context can always cause misunderstandings. It
does so in this case. Smith was not outlining the appropriate policies for
civil governments for all time and in no sense did he suggest that the
appropriate role of government in modern societies was to suppress the poor.
Quite the reverse! His entire approach to modern government was for it to cease
intervening on behalf of special interests to enrich themselves at the expense
of consumers, the majority of whom were among the poor. He saw commercial
society as a road to opulence that would spread its benefits to the family of
common labourers.
His lectures on jurisprudence, delivered at the University of Glasgow
between 1751-1764, show his historical approach to the evolution of modern
societies through four stages, each comprising a different mode of production.
He began with what his contemporaries called ‘Rude’ society, the closest
analogy of which were commonly described as represented by the North American
‘Indians’, as reported by travellers in the 17th-18th centuries, and in Africa
and the Pacific.
In contrast to the common labourer in Scotland, by modern standards a
class of people living in poverty compared to the lives of the gentry,
landlords and princes of Britain, they compared well with the ‘chiefs’ and
‘kings’ at the head of the ‘savage’ nations of America and Africa. Indeed,
Smith pointed out that the difference in living standards between the rich and
poor in Britain was not as great as the difference in living standards between
the common poor in Britain and the ‘richest’ chief in America, who ruled the
lives of thousands of his people.
It is important to realise that Smith did not ascribe these differences
in relative living standards to any kind of racial cause; the differences arose
solely because of the relatively advanced state of the division of labour
between the two modes of production. The ‘Americans’ (and Africans) were
hunters; the Scottish poor were farmers and day-labourers, living in
shepherding, agricultural and commercial societies that had developed from when
all Europeans had lived in the first age of man – hunting and gathering. It was
John Locke (1690) who said that ‘in the beginning all the world was America’.
And so it was. Every human society had started in the Hunting stage as
‘savages’, just as our distant ancestors all came from Africa.
With extremely low population densities, hominids migrated out of Africa
from about a million years ago (and became extinct), followed by humans about
200,000 years ago. There was no need for ‘governments’ as we understand them.
People were ‘free’ of coercion, except within the families and bands, but
‘enjoyed’ extremely low living standards, first as gatherers (in common with
our cousins, the primates), then as gatherer-scavengers (stone tools, primitive
co-operators) and then as gatherer-hunters, the remnants of which occupied
North and South America (but not Central America), sub-Saharan Africa, South
Asia, Pacific Islands, and Australia.
Meanwhile, and separately, human societies in India, China, north and
central Asia, and Europe went from savagery (hunting), through shepherding,
then agriculture and lastly, commerce, some societies ‘stopping’ at particular
stages (shepherding in central Asia and Arabia, North Africa), others reaching
the commercial stages, and then reverting under barbarian invasions (Persia,
Greece, Egypt, Rome, western Europe) to agriculture with the destruction of
commerce. Meanwhile, China and India's civilisations stagnated under
institutional inertia.
Crucially, Smith highlighted the increasing role of laws as each society
developed through the four stages. With hunting and gathering, laws were few,
and were settled within families; with shepherding, law were enforced by those
who possessed flocks and herds (poachers were killed); and with agriculture and
settlements, laws were devised and enforced by the first governments, mainly in
defence of property. People who grew crops protected them against theft by
those who had none. No stable society can last for long if property in
agriculture is insecure. That was the main role of civil government as it
settled disputes and adjudicated between disputants. Shepherds defended their
flocks and herds by rewarding individuals without them with subsistence;
farmers defended their fields by rewarding landless labourers in the same
manner.
Commerce grew slowly, from the continuing division of labour – surplus
food exchanged for manufactured products in bargaining – with contracts
enforced by civil government. The relapse from Roman ‘civilisation’ (a fairly
barbaric world too) into warlords and feudalism, lasted a thousand years until
commerce revived”
in the 15th-16th centuries. Smith’s Lectures in Jurisprudence (1763-4)
trace this entire period from Classical Greece-Rome to 18th-century Britain,
and also trace the growth of Liberty within ‘modern’ society as absolutist
Feudal monarchy gave way to the rule of law, Habeas Corpus, trial by Juries,
independence of the judiciary, emasculation of the powers of the monarch,
parliamentary ‘elections’ and freedom of contracting.”
Smith was talking about the origins of civil government here and how no
effective institutions for the regulation of property were put in place without
significant corruption. Further in the chapter, Smith elaborates on the
necessity of a separation of powers to ensure fair judgment of the Rule of Law
to promote egalitarian treatment. A fair justice system will ensure that both
the rich and the poor have property rights.”
GK:
Today I would add further comments, particularly regarding the defence
of property rights in history, from observation of the behaviour not just of
the poor but also of the defence of property rights by the rich against the
depredations and ambitions of other rich property owners. Any history of
dynastic quarrels from the earliest times saw law cases galore brought by property
owners against would-be suitors with claims against current owners often
requiring the civil government to intervene on one side or another.
War Lords, Kings, and Emperors were not above these quarrels. They probably represent the largest
single cause and expense of armed state interventions in much of Europe from
pre-Roman times to the 18th century, and since.
Even in the earliest times, inter-tribal warfare was common and
skirmishes over territorial rights were constant. Hence that the Left often quote this passage from Smith in
righteous indignation about the affects of civil-government on the poor is not
surprising but they seem to prefer the naked quotation to Smith’s full argument
both his Lectures on Jurisprudence and Wealth Of Nations.
Early legal judgments that settled
disputes about property rights could cover which tribal member in an
egalitarian band had the “right” to the fruit of a tree – the one who picked it
or the one who snatched it from the picker? – or the “right” to an animal in a
hunt – the one who “started” the chase or the one who claimed the body during
the hunt? And so on in their
everyday lives.
Smith discusses these and many other cases in his Lectures on
Jurisprudence. Only Left anarchists and Hard Libertarians dispute the absolute
need for civil government to support justice in civil society and that means
Civil Government and the Rule of Law.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home