Paul Walker on the "Invisible Hand" Part 2
Paul Walker of Anti-Dismal writes
“Invisible Hand 2” HERE:
“Perhaps
the point I'm trying to get at is better said by James Otteson. When discussing
Smith's essay on "Consideration Concerning the First Formation of
Languages, and the Different Genius of Original and Compounded Languages"
Otteson writes: “The reader, furthermore, would be correct to detect in this
essay the early hints of an argument that Smith will later develop into perhaps
his most powerful, what we will call the Invisible Hand Argument: individuals,
when seeking to satisfy their own localized desires will tend to behave in ways
that will also benefit other - even others they do not know and about whom they
therefore have no particular concern, and without their intending to do so.
This Invisible Hand Argument would, I
feel, be seen in Smith's work even if the actual references to the
"invisible hand" were removed.
When Otteson
goes on to talk about "What Smith Got Right" the first thing he
mentions is Smith's model of spontaneous order. Otteson argues this is made up
of several elements, one of which is "general welfare and the
"invisible hand"". Otteson says, “Smith was under no illusion
that people in their normal daily activities actually care about the general
welfare. Luckily, however, people do not have to. The nature of the unintended
system of order suggests that they will tend to conduce to the benefits of
everyone concerned regardless - at least in the long run.
So I would (says
Paul) argue that the "invisible hand" in a broad sense, permeates
Smith's works.”
Comment
Paul’s post
includes a full extract from Lost Legacy of my post of yesterday, which again
is an example of the fair treatment of contrary opinions in scholarly
debate. In his response above,
Paul gives a straightforward example of how he thinks about the issues of
Smith’s thinking and my initial remarks here are directed to that example.
James R.
Otteson is a distinguished scholar on Adam Smith for whom I have considerable
admiration, especially from my meetings with him and from his books and papers.
James Otteson. 2002. “Adam Smith’s Market Place of Life”.. Cambridge University
Press, develops a most interesting perspective on how Smith’s thinking can be
seen as much deeper than he often specifically specifically articulates,
provided the reader takes all of his surviving works into consideration,
including in this example, Smith’s essay, “Considerations Concerning the First
Formation of Languages and the Different Genius of the original and compound
Languages” (1761; published in “Lectures in Rhetoric,& etc.” 1983, which
also includes in Lecture 3, 22 November, 1762: “Origins and Progress of
Language”.
Paul describes
James Otteson’s speculative assessments of Smith on “Language” and concludes
that it describes “what we will call the Invisible Hand Argument”, without of
course mentioning the invisible hand, or what authority such a decision had
anything to do with Adam Smith. My
caution to Paul here is that subsequent interpretations of the meaning of the
“IH” may not (and I suggest” do not) explain Smith’s intended meanings.
The
“invisible hand argument” itself owes much to Robert Nozik’s, 1974, “Anarchy, State, and Utopia” (Basic Books) written by a political philosopher, from which it spread
across political philosophy and throughout economics. It was an attractive idea or concept and those economists
educated in the modern orthodox schools generally applied it to Adam Smith’s
use of the ”IH metaphor” as if Smith meant that without explicitly saying
so. Recently, for instance,
N.Emrah Aydinonat, published, 2008. “The Invisible Hand in Ecconomics: how
economists explain unintended consequences”, Routledge, with complete assurance
what Smith meant by the “invisible hand” that is conveyed by an “invisible hand
explanation”, but without the textual authority from what Smith wrote within
the grammatical confines of the role of metaphors in the English language or
with the explication of what Smith taught in his lectures in the 15 years that
he taught Rhetoric in Scotland.
I recognise that scholars since Smith are perfectly
entitled to advance their ideas, as Robert Nozik, James Otteson, Craig Smith,
Emrah Aydinonat and a multitude of others have done regarding a potentially
attractive use for the mysteries of Adam Smith’s meaning in using the
”invisible hand” as a metaphor, but I question whether it is appropriate to
back-project their ideas onto Adam Smith, as if their ideas are derivable from
Smith’s perfect sense as a metaphor in English grammar (or in Latin for that
matter).
Hence, my
continuing efforts to bring this subjet to the attention of fellow
economists. “La Lotta Continua”!
(to crib from an Italian leftist group’s posters around Rome when I worked at
FAO.
I also think
Owen hits the target too. He
writes in the comments to Paul’s post: “I also wonder if by using the invisible hand in this
way misleads us into thinking that unintended consequences are generally
positive, ignoring the very often negative consequences.” Species can die out from unintended
consequences too.
The consequences of
unintended events are not always or necessarily positive – maybe even most
times – as expressed in the popular warning: “Beware what you wish for”. Archeologists report on the detritus of previous
civilisations and earlier societies that vanished from unintended events and
consequences. I surmise that self-interest played a role in those events and
that self-interest is and was not always benign. Markets can be more benign than past civilizations but there
is no automatic certainty that they will be unless the necessary protections
are in place, especially the rule of liberty and justice, as Smith advised and “men
of system” ignored.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home