McCloskey Points the Way to Modern Smithianism
Deirdre McCloskey, Distinguished Professor of Economic, History,
English, and Communication, University of Illinois at Chicago has continued
developing her remarkable new work in significant aspects of economics
practically single-handed that never cease to amaze me. She delivered a paper, “Language and Interest
in the Economy: A White Paper on 'Humanomics'” at the January meeting of the
American Economic Association at the San Diego conference of the ASSA on 6
January 2013 (an electronic copy is available HERE [Corrected 24 March]
Quite frankly, metaphorically, I jumped for joy. At last some evidence that
someone really understands the Adam Smithian project way ahead of anybody else
that I know of. Here is the
abstract:
“Economics
ignores persuasion in the economy. The economics of asymmetric “information” or
common “knowledge” over the past 40 years reduces to costs and benefits but
bypasses persuasion, “sweet talk.” Sweet talk accounts for a quarter of
national income, and so is not mere “cheap talk.” The research would direct
economics and the numerous other social sciences influenced by economics back
towards human meaning in speech - meaning which has even in the most rigorously
behaviorist experiments been shown to matter greatly to the outcome. Sweet talk
is deeply unpredictable, which connects it to the troubled economics of
entrepreneurship, discovery, and innovation. The massive innovation leading to
the Great Fact of modern economic growth since 1800 is an important case in
point. Some economic historians are beginning to find that material causes of
the Great Fact do not work, and that changes in rhetoric such as the
Enlightenment or the Bourgeois Revaluation do. A new economic history emerges,
using all the evidence for the scientific task: books as much as bonds,
entrepreneurial courage and hope as much as managerial prudence and
temperance.”
She
also quotes from Adam Smith’s Lectures On Jurisprudence (for Wednesday, 30
March 1763, vi.56: 352):
“If
we should enquire into the principle in the human mind on which this
disposition of trucking is founded, it is clearly the naturall inclination every one
has to persuade. The
offering of a shilling, which to us appears to have so plain and simple a
meaning, is
in reality offering an argument to persuade one to do so and so as it is for
his interest.
Men always endeavour to persuade others to be of their opinion even when the
matter is of no consequence to them. If one advances any thing concerning China or
the more distant moon which
contradicts what you imagine to be true, you
immediately
try to persuade him to alter his opinion. And in this manner every one is practising
oratory on others thro the whole of his life.—You are uneasy whenever one differs
from you, and you endeavour to persuade to be of your mind; or if
you do
not it is a certain degree of self command, and to this every one is breeding
thro their
whole lives. In this manner they acquire a certain dexterity and adress in managing
their affairs, or in other words in managing of men; and this is altogether the
practise of every man in the most ordinary affairs.—This being the constant
employment
or trade of every man, in the same manner as the artizans invent simple methods
of doing their work, so will each one here endeavour
to do this work in the simplest
manner. That is bartering, by which they adress themselves to the self interest
of the person and seldom fail immediately to gain their end. The brutes have no
notion of this; the dogs, as I mentiond, by having the same object in their
view sometimes
unite their labours, but never from contract.”
This
is the missing dimension in the ideas of modern economists (and psychologists sociologists,
anthropologists and above all mathematicians – not to forget our friend, Karl
Polanyi) when analysing the bargaining problem.
This
became evident to me from a search through the literature from the 1930s
onwards when writingresearching my MSc (1972, Strathclyde University) on
‘Productivity Bargaining: a case study in an Oil Refinery’ (Shell), and afterwards, when putting together a
“Workshop Negotiations” course at Brunel University in 1975. There was virtually nothing at
all in the literature that showed evidence of economists actually observing substantial
negotiations in UK industry. The
USA was somewhat different in the pioneering work of Walton and McKersie, but
US economists had less, even nothing, to say about bargaining outside their
conflict-based pure mathematical models. My external examiner asked why there
was no “good old marginal analysis” in my thesis. I replied, living dangerously: “because it is not relevant in real world
negotiation processes I observed.”
People,
writes McCloskey, “talk” or “converse” and “in conversing they open each other
to modifications of the price” and “they establish, as we say, the ‘going’
price” and this is “how the paradoxes of continuous traders and so forth in
Arrow-Debreu formulations are solved in practice , and why experimental markets
work so amazingly well despite not satisfying the Arrow-Debreu conditions even
approximately”. … “in this manner everyone is practicing oratory on other
through the whole of his life”.
In
my research and observation for many years later in negotiation consultancy, I
estimated that over 80 per cent of the contact time spent by negotiation
partners is spent in argument/debate that sets the tone for the proposing and
bargaining phases of negotiation that
determines the quality of the agreed deal, if one is reached. If an agreement is not reached then that
80 per cent approaches 100 per cent of the contact time and, of course, no deal
results, and possibly a great deal of expense in strikes or in changing suppliers.
McCloskey
agues that persuasion has economic significance – without it gracing the
attention of ‘MAXU’ theorists.
She
writes of “sweet talk” as “honest persuasion” and reports estimates of sweet
talk at “one quarter of society’s income”. The utility maximisers cannot explain sweet talk, opening
the way for theories that everybody is a cynical selfish smart guy. For
economists the causes of the rapid growth in per capita incomes from within the
innovating market economies is an empty set. Nothing they include the that set explain enough of the
forces for change (See McCloskey’s brilliant “Bourgeois Dignity”, 2010, from Chicago UP, that tests every
pure economic notion that have been proposed for why some countries in North-West
Europe began the process of developing markets economies, while most others
didn’t, and many still haven’t. Her forthcoming book looks closer at what
initiated that long process).
I suspect that many neo-classical economists, and the
remaining socialists, including a few of Karl Polanyi’s fans, along with the new
ecologists, will call for the same old ‘solutions’ and ideologies, and dismiss
McCloskey’s thesis. I think
she is worth reading whatever your preconceived notions.
4 Comments:
The link to her paper wasn't working for me. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1889320
Steve
Apologies but that is the link on McCloskey's paper (with a '1' added at the end.
I took of an imprint from the conference and sent to me by an attendee.
I shall email McCloskey and await her response.
Apologies again
Gavin
The link is
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1889320
Lorenzo
Thanks. I shall post the link on the message.
Gavin
Post a Comment
<< Home