Finding the Correct Balance Between State and Markets
I have been engaged in a discussion with a correspondent and what follows summarises my contribution on the problems of development in developing economies. I publish on Lost Legacy because it discusses a very modern problem of the appropriate relationship between the State and the Market economy which is common in different forms and degrees in all countries:
The problem is to achieve the right balance between a competitive market
economy and an effective state: markets where possible; the state where
necessary.
Adam Smith was
quite clear that market-state roles were mutually dependent. Markets did
not have to be perfectly free and nor did the state have to be totally dominant
for both to contribute to economic growth. One without the other would
not be likely to contribute to economic success (crudely measured by a daily
income of $1 a day or less for the overwhelming majority of the world’s
population). This was true in and well beyond Europe, the first
region to raise incomes from $1 towards $100 a day for the majority of its
populations in about two centuries. That rise in per capita incomes
is now happening in more quickly in South America, Asia and even in Africa,
though at a slower rate in some places and it is taking various forms in the
countries experiencing the changes.
Smith would not
be surprised. There are large differences that remain between
individual countries, some with authoritarian states that remained
ideologically hostile to markets and their associated liberties up to recent
times. I think we can summarise Smith as being in favour of ‘markets where
possible, and state activities where necessary’. See Warren J.
Samuels and Steven G. Medema “Freeing Smith from the “Free Market”: On the
Misperception of Adam Smith on the Economic Role of Government”, History
of Political Economy, 2005 37(2): 219-226. Here is a list I extracted
from Wealth Of Nations (see by Lost Legacy Blog: 4 March 2010).
Smith’s concept
of free markets was not one of the total absence of State regulations.
Far from it. Here is the list extracted from Wealth Of Nations:
• the Navigation
Acts, blessed by Smith under the assertion that ‘defence, however, is of much
more importance than opulence’ (WN464);
• Sterling marks
on plate and stamps on linen and woollen cloth (WN138–9);
• enforcement of
contracts by a system of justice (WN720);
• wages to be
paid in money, not goods;
• regulations of
paper money in banking (WN437);
• obligations to
build party walls to prevent the spread of fire (WN324);
• rights of
farmers to send farm produce to the best market (except ‘only in the most
urgent necessity’) (WN539);
• ‘Premiums and
other encouragements to advance the linen and woollen industries’ (TMS185);
• ‘Police’, or
preservation of the ‘cleanliness of roads, streets, and to prevent the bad
effects of corruption and putrifying substances’;
• ensuring the ‘cheapness
or plenty [of provisions]’ (LJ6; 331);
• patrols by
town guards and fire fighters to watch for hazardous accidents (LJ331–2);
• erecting and
maintaining certain public works and public institutions intended to facilitate
commerce (roads, bridges, canals and harbours) (WN723);
• coinage and
the mint (WN478; 1724);
• post office
(WN724);
• regulation of
institutions, such as company structures (joint- stock companies, co-partneries,
regulated companies and so on) (WN731–58);
• temporary
monopolies, including copyright and patents, of fixed duration (WN754);
• education of
youth (‘village schools’, curriculum design and so on) (WN758–89);
• education of
people of all ages (tythes or land tax) (WN788);
• encouragement
of ‘the frequency and gaiety of publick diversions’(WN796);
• the prevention
of ‘leprosy or any other loathsome and offensive disease’ from spreading among
the population (WN787–88);
• encouragement
of martial exercises (WN786);
• registration
of mortgages for land, houses and boats over two tons (WN861, 863);
• government
restrictions on interest for borrowing (usury laws) to overcome investor ‘stupidity’
(WN356–7);
• laws against
banks issuing low-denomination promissory notes (WN324);
• natural
liberty may be breached if individuals ‘endanger the security of the whole
society’ (WN324);
• limiting ‘free
exportation of corn’ only ‘in cases of the most urgent necessity’ (‘dearth’ turning
into ‘famine’) (WN539); and
• moderate
export taxes on wool exports for government revenue (WN879).
Moving our focus
to the 19th century, I suggest you consult Murray Milgate and Shannon C,
Stimson's, 2009. “After Adam Smith: A Century of Transformation in Politics and
Political Economy, particularly pages 252-57. Princeton University Press.
While Adam Smith did not advocate laissez-faire, his name became associated
with laissez-faire from political economists after he died in 1790 (Bentham,
Ricardo, Mill, Jevons, Marshall who among economists contributed to this false
picture), plus parliamentary campaigners (The Anti-Corn Law League, Wilson
editor of The Economist, Cobden, and others). The idea appealed to 19th-century
mine and mill owners, under pressure from legislators. Also some
legislators, representing the aristocratic landed interests, who were smarting
from manufacturing interests that had conducted a successful parliamentary
campaign to repeal the Corn Laws in 1846 (which laws had kept prices of corn
high and therefore added to factory wage costs). But always remember that
their versions of laissez-faire was about freedom for merchants and
manufacturers, not for their workers or consumers. Merchants did not
favour free trade as such and because Britain enjoyed technological dominance
across the 19th-century world, they had less to fear from reducing tariffs on
manufactured imports. These ideas eventually coalesced into Empire
Preferences that kept rival imperial competitors out of the colonies.
By the mid-20th century,
neoclassical economics had formed ideas of free-market economies (that assumed
perfect competition) and had essentially come to dominate international
development thinking. The ex-colonies were managed by domestic elites and
local customs had formed local elites that tended to be comfortable in monopoly
arrangements that favoured them and their allies. Developing states
experienced much state domination in their economies a few decades ago. China was totally
state-dominant; India was riddled with government interventions (national
planning) and its economy was a long way from free markets.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home