New Thoughts On The Invisible Hand Metaphor
IMPORTANT NOTICE
I receive comments for publication referring to posts I made in 2009 and before 2007 still, suggesting that some readers, especially new readers, are using the old Lost Legacy "dot com" address. All comments welcome to the new address:
ADAM SMITH’S LOST LEGACY HAS BEEN MOVED BY “BLOGGER”, THE HOST SITE, TO A NEW ADDRESS:
TO FOLLOW ALL 2883 POSTS (AND COUNTING) FROM HERE TO 2012 AND BEYOND, PLEASE USE THE NEW ADDRESS.
THANK YOU
Gavin Kennedy
I
have argued for seven years on Lost Legacy against modern interpretations of
Adam Smith, which assert, contrary to the evidence in his books, that he
ascribed some mystical general quality to his use on only two occasions of the
well-known 17th-18th-century metaphor of an invisible
hand.
So
far I have not had much success – though the exceptions are most welcome and
for which I express my thanks for the encouragement they provide.
I
now think it is time to take the argument to those lingering on the fringes of
accepting the case I have presented on Lost Legacy since 2005.
This
means broadening my counter-argument to the modern consensus that Adam Smith’s
use was not limited to the confines of a mere metaphor; it was, they claim, a
profound statement that shook the world of academe, albeit nearly 200 years
after he had died in 1790.
Consider
Smith’s first published use of the metaphor of “an invisible hand” in his first
book, Moral Sentiments, 1759 (Part IV, chapter 1). In the course of a philosophical argument about the negative
and positive personal experiences by those who make sacrifices in pursuit of
riches, Smith refers to the “proud and unfeeling landlord”:
“It is to no purpose, that the proud
and unfeeling landlord views his extensive fields, and without a thought for
the wants of his brethren, in imagination consumes himself the whole harvest
that grows upon them. The homely and vulgar proverb, that the eye is larger
than the belly, never was more fully verified than with regard to him. The
capacity of his stomach bears no proportion to the immensity of his desires,
and will receive no more than that of the meanest peasant. The rest he
is obliged to distribute among those, who prepare, in the nicest manner, that
little which he himself makes use of, among those who fit up the palace in
which this little is to be consumed, among those who provide and keep in order
all the different baubles and trinkets, which are employed in the oeconomy of
greatness; all of whom thus derive from his luxury and caprice, that share of
the necessaries of life, which they would in vain have expected from his
humanity or his justice. The produce of the soil maintains at all times nearly
that number of inhabitants which it is capable of maintaining. The rich only
select from the heap what is most precious and agreeable. They consume little
more than the poor, and in spite of their natural selfishness and rapacity,
though they mean only their own conveniency, though the sole end which they
propose from the labours of all the thousands whom they employ, be the
gratification of their own vain and insatiable desires, they divide with the
poor the produce of all their improvements. They are led by an invisible hand
to make nearly the same distribution of the necessaries of life, which would
have been made, had the earth been divided into equal portions among all its
inhabitants, and thus without intending it, without knowing it, advance the
interest of the society, and afford means to the multiplication of the species.
When Providence divided the earth among a few lordly masters, it neither forgot
nor abandoned those who seemed to have been left out in the partition. These
last too enjoy their share of all that it produces. In what constitutes the
real happiness of human life, they are in no respect inferior to those who
would seem so much above them. In ease of body and peace of mind, all the
different ranks of life are nearly upon a level, and the beggar, who suns
himself by the side of the highway, possesses that security which kings are
fighting for” (TMS IV.1.10: 183-4).
In the
academic literature dealing with this quotation the “invisible hand” is deemed
to be variously, “the hand of god”, “Providence”, “the IH of the market”, “a
presumption of liberty”, “a metaphor for national defense”, and many others
(the latest, from Daniel Klein being it was an “allegory”).
I have argued, in debate with academic colleagues of
various persuasions, that the IH metaphor is exactly that, a metaphor following
the rules of English grammar. (For example, see Kennedy, G. “Adam Smith and the
Role of the Metaphor of an Invisible Hand”, Economic Affairs, vo. 31, no 1.
2011). In support of this
argument, I refer to Adam Smith on metaphors in his “Lectures on Rhetoric and
Belles Lettres” [1762] 1983, p. 29, in which he states that a metaphor
describes in a “more striking and interesting manner its object”. This
corresponds to the modern meaning of a metaphor given in the definitive Oxford
English Dictionary.
What is the object of the IH metaphor in the above TMS
quotation? In the answer lies the
resolution of this debate turns. To my disappointment, no one has challenged
Smith’s interpretation – they have simply ignored it.
I identify the object of the IH metaphor in TMS as the
absolute necessity of the landlord to feed his retainers, servants, and serfs
(later his tenants). Why is he
compelled to distribute some of his harvests to the “thousands whom he
employs”? If he didn’t feed them
how would they be able to work?
And if they didn’t work upon whom would the “proud and unfeeling
landlord” depend on to prepare, seed, tend, and harvest his fields? If they were not fed they could not
labour, and if they didn’t labour they, and their families, would not be fed. This mutual dependence is so obvious
that I cannot see why my colleagues, in no way lacking the highest
qualifications as senior academics, disregard the obvious in Smith’s meaning of
his use of the invisible hand metaphor, to describe this mutual dependence in a
“more striking and interesting manner”.
So let me draw further on Adam Smith to elucidate the
nature of the relationship throughout the ages of shepherding and farming, much
of it spent under regimes far more tyrannical than anything experienced since
the appearance of commercial societies.
I turn to Adam Smith in the little read Book III of Wealth Of
Nations.
This extract gives a more factual historical account
of the period covered by the feudal landlordism relevant to the time pictured
by Smith when he described the regular behaviour of the “proud and unfeeling
landlord” in “Moral Sentiments” of his being “led by an invisible hand” to
share part of his harvest with the “thousands he employed”. It reinforces my assertion that the
metaphor describes in a “more striking and interesting manner” the nature of
the landlord’s relationship with his serfs.
“In a country which has neither foreign commerce, nor
any of the finer manufactures, a great proprietor, having nothing for which he can ex-change the greater part
of the produce of his lands
which is over and above the maintenance of the cultivators, consumes the whole in rustick hospitality at home. If this surplus produce is sufficient to maintain a hundred or a thousand men, he can make use of it in no other way than by maintaining a hundred or a thousand men. He is at all times, therefore, surrounded with a multitude of retainers and dependants, who having no equivalent to give in return for
their maintenance, but being fed entirely by his bounty, must obey him, for the same reason that
soldiers must obey the prince who pays them. …
…. A tenant
at will, who possesses land sufficient to maintain his
family for little more than a quit-rent, is as dependent upon the proprietor as any servant or retainer whatever, and must obey him with as little
reserve. Such a proprietor, as
he feeds his servants and retainers at his own house, so he feeds his tenants at their houses. The subsistence of both is derived from his bounty, and its continuance depends upon
his good pleasure. ….
…. But what all the violence of the feudal institutions
could never have effected, the silent and insensible operation of foreign commerce and manufactures gradually brought about. These
gradually furnished the great proprietors with something for which they could exchange the whole
surplus produce of their lands, and which they could consume themselves without sharing it either with
tenants or retainers. All for ourselves, and nothing for other people, seems,
in every age of the world, to have been the
vile maxim of the masters of mankind. As soon, therefore, as they could find a method of consuming
the whole value of their rents themselves, they had no disposition to share them with any other persons” (WN III.iv.10)
The consequence over time,
of “the silent and insensible operation
of foreign commerce and manufactures gradually
brought about”, was the reduction in the manpower base of the landlords. These people were previously employed
about the property; the men were mobilised in time of his need of a military
force against rival landlords within the
aristocratic orders of the feudal structure at home and abroad, and, on
occasion, during regime instability, against the King. Dynastic quarrels were
endemic over the millennia.
But note, Smith described the sharing of the
landlord’s harvests with the ‘thousands he employed’ in his service as the
landlord being “led by an invisible hand” to do so. That was an attractive metaphor for the necessity that led
him to do so, by describing in a “more striking and interesting manner” the
mutual dependence of those involved.
It certainly was not visible.
So the IH metaphor did its work remarkably well, so well that modern
economists don’t see what is going on.
They invent other, often mystical quasi-theological explanations (‘there
is an actual invisible hand’ at work) beside the clear and simple grammatical
role of Smith using a metaphor.
Yet, here, in Wealth Of Nations, he describes another
situation where “the silent and insensible operation of foreign commerce and manufactures gradually brought about”
another consequence of immense historic importance for the gradual intrusion of
“foreign commerce and manufactures” (i.e., a new, 4th, stage in the
history of humans), that caused the decline in the feudal powers of an
important older order that acted as a barrier to the revived commercial society
that had been destroyed by the decline and fall of Rome in the 5th
century. This interregnum lasted through to the 15th century, first
as allodial successive war-lords, where tenure lasted to whomsoever could hold
it against all challengers, then as
feudal tenures subject to the pleasure of dynastic kings.
4 Comments:
I saw a visual metaphor yesterday in an art gallery. It was Pablo Picasso's representation of a bull. He used a bicycle seat for its head and bicycle handle bars for it horns. There was no mistaking the representation.
Now if only we could do that with the invisible hand metaphor.
airth
You saw a visual representation of a bull. Nothing more.
The IH does not exist except in your imagination, not mine.
Gavin
Jeremy001
Thanks for commenting, See Lost Legacy every day.
I am not sure what more information you seek.
Gavin
Gavin
"You saw a visual representation of a bull. Nothing more."
Nevertheless, in the art world it is called a visual metaphor.
"The IH does not exist except in your imagination, not mine."
That's pretty haunting stuff!
Post a Comment
<< Home