A Case of Entreprenurial Innovation
Of interest, perhaps,
to historians of economic thought in modern debates about entrepreneurial
innovation, Wayne Lewchuk authored this entry in the 0xford Dictionary of
National Bibliography (oxforddnb-lotd@oup.com)
showing early 20th-century attempts at mass production in the
nascent motorcar industry, then slowly developing in England at the Cowley,
Oxford.
Of particular interest
is the key role of the innovator-engineer aligned with an entrepreneurial a business
owner in conditions of a developing mass market for a new transport technology.
He writes:
“Frank George Woollard,
(1883-1957), developer of mass production, was born in London, the son of George
Woollard, general steward to a firm of private bankers, and his wife, Emily
Constance, nee Powell. He was educated at the City of London School and
Goldsmiths and Birkbeck colleges. Between 1900 and 1905 he was apprenticed to
Dugald Drummond with the London and South Western Railway (LSWR) at Eastleigh,
Hampshire. There he was exposed to two factors that would shape his future
career: he was involved in the design of an early motorized vehicle, the
Clarkson Steam Omnibus, and he also witnessed the introduction of a crude
assembly line in 1904 to manufacture all steel coaches. The cycle time on this
line was seven and one-third hours, a factor which encouraged Woollard later in
his career to consider flow production techniques in the British automobile
industry despite relatively short production runs.
… During the First
World War, he was responsible for the production of tank gearboxes, his first
exposure to producing large numbers of standardized products. After the war, he
supervised a contract to manufacture front and rear axles, and gearboxes for
the Morris Cowley. Production was reorganized along flow lines to meet Morris's
demands.
In 1923 Woollard left
Wrigley to become director and general manager of the engine branch of Morris
Motors Ltd. His first task was to reorganize the old Hotchkiss plant in Coventry.
With the use of flow production assembly techniques, within a year output
increased from 300 to 1200 engines per week. In early 1924 the machinery used
to manufacture engine blocks, the heaviest and most complex component of an
engine, was reorganized and placed in order according to the sequence of
individual operations. Initially, the machines were linked with hand conveyors
and workers manually pushed blocks between production stations. In late 1924 a
bold step was taken towards automated production with the introduction of a
hydraulic system which automatically moved blocks between stations, clamped
them into fixtures, and sequenced the machines.
Woollard had
appreciated that such a system offered advantages in the areas of planning and
co-ordination, and in the control of labour, giving management more authority
to set the pace of work. He believed that such control would be accepted by the
workforce if it was accompanied by rising living standards. At the time, this
was itself almost as radical a concept as the shift to automated production.
Woollard's innovative use of automatic transfer machinery had to be abandoned
because of failures in the electric, hydraulic, and pneumatic control
mechanisms. However, he paved the way for Ford to implement a similar system in
Detroit some twenty years later.”
Comment
Completely new
production technologies for new consumer products can create whole new products
(if successful in attracting consumer demand sufficient to attract capital and
an appropriate workforce at least minimally profitable prices).
Entrepreneurs who
identify and can exploit the means to supply such opportunities can thrive on
their vision, but ‘many are called but few are chosen’, as old-style preachers
used to warn their flock. The survivors come and go – think of the original computer
giants in early computing power like DEC, Digital and IBM, or the smaller firms
like Apple, Prime, Wang and also the many rivals to Microsoft.
Frank Woollard was in
the engineering-led, early motorcar manufacturing industry. He was also part of the beneficiaries
from increasing-returns of innovation in both manufacturing processes and in
product designs.
Nobody can plan dispersed
innovation, especially not those in government-led committees – while the are
sitting taking minutes of their meetings, the real world keeps turning and among the
countless dispersed entrepreneurs in markets some are thinking ‘outside the box’, as
they say. Some few of them restlessly seize what they believe are
opportunities, not just contemplating the ‘ifs’ of what they could have done, ‘if
only’.
They just do it!
That is
the power of markets in free societies, though not necessarily those with
utopian notions of so-called perfectly free-markets in Economics 101.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home