Tim Worstall Thinks Outside the Box and Looks Outside His Window
Tim Worstall does it
again over at The Pin Factory Blog for the Adam Smith Institute:
“What regulation does is favour both the
incumbents in any activity and also large companies in anytihng at all. For
what worries business is not whether they're allowed to do something or not:
but that other people will find a better way of doing it and thus compete. More
regulation means that fewer upstarts can enter the market and any that do are
hobbled by that regulation. The more regulation the more the current large
companies can continue to be capitalist without having to worry about their
practices being tempered by that market competition.”
Comment
Counter-intuitive
it may be but Tim often thinks that way and its good for economics that he
does.
Too
much is taken for granted about regulation being a negative influence in
markets and that business has good reason to oppose all regulations, or at
least to resist adding to those that exist.
There
certainly is a general presumption against regulation among the centre-right,
and beyond, people whom I also meet and contra-wise, a presumption favouring
more regulations to keep capitalists honest among centre-left, and beyond, whom
I also meet (I am student of abnormal political beliefs and fantasies).
Adam
Smith showed both sides on state initiated regulations. He advised regulations as a sub-set of
laws where they were appropriate as in weight and measures, assay testing,
postal services, firewalls, and interest limits, foe example. He opposed regulations when they
interfered in competitive markets, or supported monopolistic and
anti-competitive measures.
Both of these were lobbied for by business interests, supported by
employees, or, to a lesser extent, consumer interests.
Tim
Worstall raises a relevant and observable point (see the above link). Business is much more highly stratified
in terms of the range from smallest to largest in today’s market economies
compared to business enterprises in the 18th-century - not all capitalist businesses think and act alike (nor do all consumers think alike or have identical notions of their self-interests. This has consequences, which
incidentally were present in nascent form in Smith’s days and before. He described how some Merchants and Manufacturers could and
did lobby legislators for regulations that created forms of protection for them
by narrowing the competition.
So
today markets are lumbered with various trade associations, which recruit
businesses to serve their common interests. Thus, small groceries and related
business might form a trade association, hiring a number of fulltime employees
to press the interests of the members, each of whom pay subscriptions to the
association. In time, small, local
trade associations may join similar local associations to form a national
association, raising more substantial funds to professionise its national
officers, widen its administrative staff, and eventually afford more plush
headquarters, and develop contacts with legislators to promote its agenda.
The
personnel at the top of the numerous trade associations may themselves form
their own trade association to represent their own agenda with the
government. This agenda need not
be at variance with the agendi of the managers’ individual parent trade associations. They could be joining together to
give their own parent bodies more political weight, given that these bodies
have common interests.
Consider
the protection aspects of these trends.
The definition of who is a ‘member’ also defines who is not a
member.
Adam Smith saw the
Apprentices Statutes from Elizabethan times as a major impediment of competition;
skilled tradesmen could not practise their trade in a town where they had not
served their apprenticeship, thus severely cutting potential competition that would have benefited consumers.
We
also see similar anti-competitive measures from trade associations that
persuade legislators to make rules defining their products or the minimum size
of their plants or farms or turnover to qualify for official recognition, which
have the side-benefit (assuming it isn’t their main purpose!) of restricting
competitors to existing established larger businesses.
Smith, of course, drew attention to
this phenomenon in Wealth of Nations in his remarks about men of the same trade "seldom meet together for merriment or diversion" without the conversation
turning into a conspiracy to raise prices. Local and national trade
associations have long provided a respectable facility for such meetings.
Tim
Worstall provides a cogent argument for why big businesses supports such
lucrative lobbying for more regulations, and the costlier they are to comply
with, monitor, and report, the better. These costs act as a barrier to entry
for new, inevitably smaller start-ups and innovators across industry (thus undermining the Hayekian economy and sheltering big business from Schumpeter's "perennial gale of creative destruction". I think Tim is on to something
anomalous here, contrary to the regular political agitation to reduce the gale
of regulation in business against which, supposedly, big business is opposed.
I’ve certainly have not yet met a capitalist bureaucrat who supports competition
that threatens to damage her business.
Not so strange when you think of it. Business moguls are seldom libertarians, moderate like me or extreme like others. And scratch below the surface, those that claim to support laissez-faire are more than a little selective in just who should enjoy laissez-faire. In the 18th century, town merchants in France demanded laissez-faire from the heavy hand of state sponsored regulations for themselves, not their customers. M. Le Gendres' speech to Minister Colbert was 'laissez-nous faire" (leave us - the merchants - alone). Similarly with the employers' laissez-faire agitation against the Factory Acts limiting the 12-hour + working days in the mills and mines for employees, or the laissez-faire agitation against the Corn Laws by urban business interests, though not by the farmers who would be affected by falling food prices (good news for Manchester mill owners, though less so for their workers whose wages would be cut in consequence). Which is probably why Adam Smith never argued for laissez-faire or even use the words. He was a universal principled libertarian, never an ideologue.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home