A Must Read New Book on Friedrich Hayek
Eamonn Butler: “Friedrich Hayek: the ideas and influence of the
libertarian economist”,
Harriman House: Petersfield, Hampshire, in association
with the Institute of Economic Affairs, London
ISBN 978-0857191755. £14.99.
The publisher describes Eamonn Butler’s “Friedrich Hayek” as “a breath
of intellectual fresh air”. I
concur, for Butler is refreshingly easy to read. He is a brilliant communicator and needs to be to
compress Hayek’s many volumes of his lifetime’s writings into 146 pages and
hold his readers’ attention. Scholars familiar with Hayek’s works and general
readers exposed to them for the first time will find much here worthy of their
attention.
Friedrich Hayek (1899-1992) lived through the turbulent years of two
world wars, the Russian revolution and its socialist experiments, the great
inflation in Weimar Germany, the rise of the Nazis to power, the Austrian
“Anschluss” and the Holocaust, the ensuing Cold War from the expansion of
communism in Eastern Europe and Asia, the failures of state planning by Western
social-democratic governments, and the fall of the Berlin Wall. Not surprisingly, perhaps, much of
Hayek’s intellectual work focussed on the great socialist ‘mistake’ of central
planning (‘The Road to Serfdom’, 1944) versus the case for liberty and free
markets (‘The Constitution of Liberty’, 1960.
Holding to his unfashionable convictions for decades led Hayek into
intellectual isolation. He was, albeit, politely tolerated rather than listened
to by faculty in the universities he taught at. Mainstream economics passed him by during
the Keynesian years. Nobody, for
example, mentioned him during my undergraduate years from 1965-69. More is the
pity. I found much in Butler’s
book that explained a lot about mid-twentieth-century controversies between Keynes’s
and Friedman’s economics, which I would have understood better if I had read
him at university.
Hayek contributed original thinking to philosophy and to neuroscience,
which brought him close to Adam Smith’s works in the 18th century,
such as his theories about the emergence of morality from childhood (‘self
command’) and as an adult (the ‘impartial spectator’), the origins of language
and how knowledge evolves, and of course, the origins of the wealth of nations.
Hayek’s intellectual isolation (described by Eamonn Butler as his
“wilderness years”) brought a few like-minded academics and, crucially,
centre-right politicians (Thatcher and Reagan) into touch with him. Think tanks were funded to spread debate
on the application of Hayek’s ideas, such as the Institute of Economic Affairs,
which offered a barrage of pamphlets on the unsuccessful state planning
attempted by Labour governments.
Later, influenced by Hayek’s ideas, Eamonn Butler founded the Adam Smith
Institute (disclosure: of which I am a Fellow) to promote interest in
free-market ideas applied to a wide-ranging critical commentary on both
conservative and labour governments.
Hayek’s life and legacy testify to the lasting power of ideas over the
fleeting influence of individual politicians who, because they misunderstand
the dynamics of human societies, normally promote the wrong ideas. Radicals of
Left and Right believe they can change society by capturing the legislature to
correct what they regard as society’s systemic errors. Hayek noted,
sardonically, that if designed changes tried to change the world, we cannot be
sure that the outcome would please either its designers or those affected by
their changes.
Hayek insisted that human institutions throughout history were the
result of countless individual human actions, but not from anyone’s deliberate
designs. Yet while human
institutions from the primitive to the most complex have some sort of order
within them, it does not follow that they were or can be deliberately
invented. Hayek called the process
through which societies formed over time examples of “spontaneous order”. Adam
Smith remarked that a society of murderers and robbers would have to refrain
from murdering or robbing each other. Rules of justice evolve and vary, and
those societies that manage spontaneously to absorb evolutionary changes in
their rules tend to grow more successfully that those that do not. A group of hunters evolve rules for
sharing the hunt and by staying small in number (30 perhaps) they work within
the limits of mutual trust. The
rules of a society of millions are much more complex and history shows how the
laws of justice evolve and become more numerous over time (the Ten Commandments
were never enough). Hayek affirmed
that a free society was not one without rules or government – rulers and
citizens remain constrained by the predictable rule of law, not the whims of
designers.
It is in his accounts of why markets flourish naturally that Hayek is
most persuasive, and Butler is at his best in showing the importance of this
side of Hayek’s work. This means
discussing socialism, which at first glance is a debate about a past that is
now over. However, lessons from the endemic failures of socialism are in excellent
contrast to the superior results of market capitalism, and Butler develops the
contrast clearly, highlighting the untold damage done by the rising tide of
deliberate rule changes that eventually clog the operations of markets,
restraining them from their full potential.
Socialism is a mistaken response to how societies evolve and work. The “battle lines” may have
changed from what they were in the 19th century when socialism was
an untried idea, but having been tried and failed in the 20th
century, the central problem remains today: how does a central agency manage a
complex economy? Socialism necessarily means dispensing with an existing market
capitalism, which whatever else is regarded as dispensable, the visible success
of markets that grew within the margins of the millennia-old human experiences
since our ancestors left the forest and plains to become shepherds and farmers
10,000 years ago, suggests that markets are dispensed with at an enormous
cost. We can contrast the
experience of China and Britain since the 15th century; China’s
government deliberately ended foreign trade despite its massive technological
lead. Meanwhile individuals in
Britain continued trading and eventually re-discovered the ‘lost’ technologies
of China which led to the spread of local markets, science and unheard of new
technologies. Market capitalism
flourishes under conditions of constitutional liberty more than totalitarian
socialism can flourish by destroying markets.
In founding permanent settlements, where hunting, scavenging and
farming were necessarily less important, a new way to subsistence was found
spontaneously. This was through
markets, where individuals ‘exchange’ on the simple rule that each individual,
household, community or locality exchanged things they valued less for that
which they valued more. This is no
zero sum rule where only one trader benefits from the exchange; each offers
what they value less to gain what they value more from those who voluntarily
offer to exchange with them for something they value more. Markets allow both parties to gain,
which historically was a completely new set of rules, discovered spontaneously
and not invented by anyone. What works once, they try again, and again.
Voluntary exchange in turn, writes Butler, “allowed people to specialise in
producing particular goods and services for exchange; they could then develop
their skills and tools and so make their production more efficient. And this greater productivity generated
greater [mutual] wealth, on which the population could grow” (p 32).
This also created the new morality different from just accepting what
their “betters” allowed them for their lifelong slavish servitude. The “old morality” was challenged by
the “new free exchange morality” and, eventually, the new market morality broke
through, first in Britain, later in Europe and North America. It is now spreading and deepening by
countries ditching socialism and mimicking capitalist markets across a
developing world, like India, China, and Brazil. The historical results under
markets are astonishing. The
majority of labourers, living in poverty under the rule of warlords, lived
their very short lives on under $1 a day (in occasional “good times” on as much
as $3 a day). Unlike their
ancestors, who were dependent on a barely changing economics for millennia,
those few living around 1800 in a corner of North West Europe, began to
experience the effects of the new market capitalism as it grew and spread, and
which gradually lifted the per capita income of their descendants to upwards of $100 a day by the
21st century. No such results were experienced in the historic past
for any large proportion of the world’s populations, certainly not by rival
socialist economic systems, nor by mercantile, hyper-protected economies, as
have been tried throughout the recent past.
Markets work by the very visible price system that spurs people to
produce what consumers’ want, which consumers may choose to buy voluntarily
among competing offers of what is available. Prices “encapsulate all the information that producers and
consumers need” to produce what consumers might want, and for consumers to
select from what producers discover is, or can be, made available for sale at a
profit. No central planning
authority, whatever their intentions, can possibly know enough about the
dispersed details by which of billions of products, and their technologies work
to satisfy the objectives of the billions of individuals close to the way
markets manage to answer those tasks daily. Planning authorities, at best, fail to reach their own
targets, even with the most powerful computers ever built. Mostly they don’t
even manage to match market-produced products and services in quality or
quantity, manifested in the one-way dash to emigrate from poorer non-market
countries into the market countries.
These desperate people would rather be a minority of poor in a rich
country than remain part of the majority of poor in a poor country. The famous “Iron Curtain”, we remember,
was primarily to keep its citizens inside the Soviet Union rather than to keep
foreigners out.
Hayek showed why socialist economies are made obsolete by the their
inability to acquire sufficient knowledge even to produce a simple product by
central command, without creating massive distortions to the production of
other goods. Markets undertake such tasks all the time because they fit well
with the dispersed knowledge shown by visible prices along the interlinked
supply chains that make up competitive market economies. Profit rewards those
who discover better ways of producing what consumers are prepared to pay
for. No central plan, no amount of
computational genius, no advanced mathematics, can capture for a moment the
dispersed knowledge or shifting tastes that constitutes what happens across
whole economies. Hayek called the
belief among the Left that it could be done by planners their “fatal
conceit”. He agreed with Adam
Smith that market prices gravitate towards but never need to settle at an ideal
balance.
Hayek, of course, wrote about much more and this short book covers
Hayek’s range brilliantly. I
recommend Eamonn Butler’s “Friedrich Hayek: the ideas and influence of a
libertarian economist” without hesitation. I only wish it had been available to
me fifty years ago when I had to waste the next fifteen years reading and
teaching Keynesian public finance and state-funded economic development.
Gavin Kennedy Emeritus Professor, Edinburgh Business School,
Heriot-Watt University
3 Comments:
It looks like another interesting read to add to my long list. Good review.
SM
Thank you.
Read it; you won't be disappointed.
I began reading Hayek in the 90s when I purchased a set of his books in a sale from Routledge (several volumes), which I read through in a couple of summers in France.
Starting randomly, I probably did not give them a fair chance, which is where Butler's short monograph would have been so handy, as I had no context to guide me.
They are still in my library down there, so I shall start over again.
Let me know how you get on with Eamonn's book.
Gavin
Will do, but it may take awhile getting around to reading this book. I'm still working my way through Smith.
Post a Comment
<< Home