Do Such People Understand Adam Smith?
Scott Cooney writes, Adjunct Professor of Sustainability at the University
of Hawaii, “Inspired Economist” HERE
“Where conservative
capitalism breaks down: Three primary sources of free market failure”
“Many people criticize policies and elected
officials based on strong support for what they believe to be free market
capitalism. But do these people actually understand capitalism? What they
believe to be capitalism: getting the government off the back of the private
sector, is not true free market capitalism. …
Adam Smith, the man
many in the conservative arena espouse to be the father of modern capitalism,
was an 18th century economist who wrote an influential book called The Wealth of Nations. In it, he
argues three main tenets. These principles have become the standards by which
capitalism, as we know it (and many peoples’ level of acceptance of it) is
measured.
The first is the invisible hand. Smith argued that there is an invisible force at play in the market
that guides production. ... The second
principle Smith espoused is that the
free market alone should determine the types and quantities of goods and
services (meaning that government should never make those decisions)…
… His third
principle was that, if all individuals
were striving for their own self-interest, that cumulatively, those efforts
would have the greatest overall good for society. By working really
hard, these folks would create economic opportunities for themselves and
others, and that provided the best overall benefit.”
“ If Smith lived
today, his theories would likely have taken into account three main sources of
free market failure:
Externalities. Externalities are
costs associated with something that are not paid for by that something. … Tragedy of the Commons. This is a
phenomenon where, if no one is governing the use of a common resource, then
what is to stop companies from exploiting it to its fullest? … Information asymmetry. Adam Smith’s
theories only hold water if everyone involved has equal access to information
on which to make decisions relevant to the market. “
“About
Scott Cooney Scott Cooney (twitter: scottcooney) is a
green business startup coach,
author of Build a Green Small Business: Profitable Ways to Become an
Ecopreneur (McGraw-Hill), and developer of the sustainability board game GBO Hawai'i.
Scott is a vegetarian, an avid cyclist, and an organic gardener.” Follow the Link.
Comment
What a travesty of
Adam Smith’s economics and his moral philosophy! One without the other is like a carriage without a horse (a
simile!).
Adam Smith never
said there was an “invisible force” at work. He used a metaphor of “an invisible hand” (popular in the 18th
century and used widely, mainly by theologians) on two occasions only to
“describe in a more striking and interesting manner” (Smith, "Lectures on Rhetoric", 1762, 1983, p 29), two instances in two
quite separate instances, separated by centuries, where the individuals
concerned – “a proud and unfeeling landlord” forget he shared his crop, and an18th-century “merchant” - worried about the security of his capital if he sent it abroad in “foreign
trade”, acted to protect their interests.
The landlord was forced by circumstances
to provide food for “the thousands they employed”, because without food they
could not labour on his lands, and the merchant was led by his insecurity to
avoid foreign trade and invest domestically. The unintended outcome of their privately motivated behaviour
was that they and their peasants had a means to live and thrive through
successive the generations, thus propagating “the multiplication of the
species” (Moral Sentiments, IV.i.10: 183) (Smith clearly disapproved of the
landlords’ arrogance generally). The
merchant’s contribution to domestic industry helped to increase “domestick
revenue and employment” (Wealth Of Nations, IV.ii.9: 456).
Smith said nothing
about a general “invisible force” at work; the metaphor could be used in other
instances where unintended consequences were occasioned and where the invisible-hand
metaphor may be appropriate. But
beyond doubt, general “self-interested” actions need not benefit society at all.
Indeed, 18th century society was afflicted by mercantile general self-interests
promoted by merchants, manufacturers and governments that were directly and
indirectly contrary to the interests of consumers, through intentional tariffs
and prohibitions, which in no sense “benefitted” a society. The claim that self-interests, sometimes
even claimed to include “selfish” actions (Paul Samuelson, 1948) benefitted
society is a false proposition, widely used by people ignorant (not too strong
a word) of the actual writings of Adam Smith, who project onto Adam Smith their
own ideas or simply mimic "prestigious" others.
It is factually
inaccurate to pretend that Adam Smith thought the “the
free market alone should determine the types and quantities of goods and
services (meaning that government should never make those
decisions)”. He gave several
examples of the government’s appropriate role in deciding which types of goods
and services should be decided by government (see Wealth Of Nations: on the
Navigation Acts (WN, 464); (Sterling Marks on plate and bullion (WN 138-9); regulations of paper money in banking (WN437);
obligations to build party walls to prevent the spread of fire (WN324);
erecting and maintaining certain public works and public institutions intended
to facilitate commerce (roads, bridges, canals and harbours) (WN723); ‘Premiums
and other encouragements to advance the linen and woollen industries’ (TMS185);
coinage and the mint (WN478; 1724); post office (WN724); registration of
mortgages for land, houses and boats over two tons (WN861, 863); laws against
banks issuing low-denomination promissory notes (WN324) and sixteen
other instances. He agreed that these
regulations “interfered” with “natural liberty”, but they were necessary for an
economy to function for the public good.
The assertion that
by “working really hard, these folks would create economic opportunities for
themselves and others, and that provided the best overall benefit” is
counter-factual as shown by Adam Smith’s “violent” (his word) attack on
mercantile political economy operating in 18th-century Britain.
As for Scott Cooney’s
thoughts on “externalities”, the
“tragedy of the Commons”, and
“information asymmetry”, his glaring misunderstanding of economics is
worrying. It is the absence of
property rights, not their presence that is the main cause of the problems
created by these issues. Nobody “owns” pollution, therefore included in the
remedy is the legal compulsion of those creating the pollution to “own” it and
clean it up. Nobody “owns” the
commons, therefore assign/sell/auction license ownership and therefore allow the owners to charge
for usage, thus reducing over-exploitation of the “free” good. Markets are the
best means of reducing “asymmetry’ through competition among suppliers, which,
of course, takes time, but attempts to force social exchanges usually make
things worse as much as the absence of markets always makes things worse in
perpetuity. Elementary Economics 101!
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home